What Causes the Pay Gap? (wage gap series, part 3)

(This is one of a series of posts on the wage gap.)

First of all, let’s dispel one common misunderstanding: the pay gap between women and men is not primarily caused by unequal pay for identical jobs. This does occasionally happen, but equal pay laws have by and large eliminated this form of obvious wage discrimination.

So what does cause the pay gap? There’s no simple answer to that question, because all sorts of factors go into creating the pay gap – and, making things more confusing, the different factors inter-relate. Let’s look at what some of those factors are.

Occupational Segregation

First, occupational segregation, in which women and men, due to social structures and also hiring discrimination, are “steered” into certain jobs. This causes some jobs (like child care worker) to be female-dominated, while other jobs (like truck driver) are male-dominated.

For example: In Philadelphia, social scientists sent fictional, equally-qualified resumes to different restaurants. The only important difference between the resumes they sent out was if the name at the top was a woman’s or a man’s. They found that snootier, higher-paying restaurants preferred to hire men, while low-paying places (diners and the like) preferred women. In this way, women were steered into a lower-paying job category: that’s job segregation.

Why does “occupational segregation” matter? It matters because workers in “women’s jobs” are paid less than workers in “men’s jobs.” As journalist Naomi Barko put it, “the biggest reason for the pay gap is not discrimination against individual women but rather discrimination against women’s occupations.” The more women work in a job, the lower the pay in that job is likely to be. (Paradoxically, this means that some men – men in female-dominated workplaces or job positions – are in effect paid less because of discrimination against jobs done by women!)

How much lower is the pay in “women’s jobs”? Different economists have calculated it different ways. The economist Paula England looked at data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (a U.S. government study that measures changes in people’s lives over time), and found that if a white woman in an all-male workplace moved to an all-female workplace, she’d lose 7% of her wages. If a black woman did the same thing, she’s lose 19% of her wages. The economists Deborah Figart and June Lapidus found that if female-dominated jobs had no wage penalty, women’s median hourly pay nationwide would go up 13.2% (men’s pay would go up 1.1%, due to raises for men working in “women’s jobs”).

Different Choices

As anti-feminists often point out, women and men often make different choices: in college major, in hours and years worked, and in what jobs to take. It’s not true that these “free choice” factors account for all of the wage gap, but they certainly account for some of it.

It’s often claimed that these “free choice” factors have nothing to do with sexism (usually this claim is made by people who want you to believe that the wage gap is nothing to be concerned about), because the choices are made by women, not by women’s employers. The reality isn’t so clear-cut, because the choices women and men in our society make aren’t made free of sexism.

For example, full-time year-round women workers work fewer hours than their male counterparts. In 1995, among workers who usually work full-time, men worked 44.5 hours per week on average while women worked 40.8 hours a week on average. Put another way, women worked 92% as many hours as men. (Source: Rones et al).

Anti-feminists claim that this shows that women make less money than men because they choose to work less. This is partly true, but it’s not the whole story. In reality, employers have at least as much to do with how many hours a particular full-time employee works as the employee’s choices. It is employers who decide who is and who is not offered overtime, for example. So while critics of feminism assume that how many hours one works is entirely the employee’s choice, actually we have no way of knowing how much of women’s fewer hours is due to women’s choices, and how much is due to discrimination in who is offered hours of work.

Another example is caretaking. Women are expected to be caretakers – both of children and of any other relatives in need of aid (elderly relatives, for example) – and to do the majority of the housework. This isn’t an example of employers discriminating against women, but it is a society-wide sexism that contributes to the wage gap. The person doing the lioness’ share of the unpaid caretaking work has far less time available for paid work; if men and women divided unpaid caretaking work equally, the paid work would be a lot more equal too. (Like many instances of sexism, this arguably harms both sexes: men are harmed by this same sexist belief because they are expected to work more and robbed of equal contact with their family.)

Nonetheless, even single women without children earn less than similar men, on average. (See, for example, Wood et al’s study of similar male and female lawyers).

Men Get More Credit for Their Work

Men’s work tends to be evaluated as higher-quality than equally-good or better women’s work. This can impact who is offered mentoring, who is assigned a job assignment, who is offered a promotion, and so on – and all of these factors in turn have an effect on the pay gap.

For example, one study of credit in the sciences, published in Nature, looked at productivity (measured in terms of publications in scientific journals, how many times a person was a “lead author” of an article, and how often the articles were cited in scientific journals) and sex. These factors were then compared to how an actual scientific review panel measured scientific competence when deciding on research grants. The results? Female scientists needed to be at least twice as accomplished as their male counterparts to be given equal credit.

Other studies have found similar results (see the bottom of this post for some citations). Men are simply given more credit for their work than women are.

Feedback Effects

To whatever extent some women freely choose to stay out of the labor market, the choice isn’t made in a void. The fact that women – even non-mothers – get rewarded less for wage-work than men means that women give less up if they choose to trade off paid work for motherhood. Women’s lower pay means women have less reason to stay in the paid work market.

This manifests itself every time a married couple, for whatever reason, has to decide to prioritize one spouse’s pay (and career path) above the other’s. If a couple has to choose whether or not to move to further one spouse’s career, all else being equal they will make whichever choice favors the higher-earning spouse. Similarly, if one person needs to take time off from work to take care of parents, grandparents or children, it makes sense for it to be the lower-paid person. But in most cases, the person with lower pay will turn out to be the woman.

Furthermore, the effect is additive – if a woman makes a sacrifice even once in her career for the couple’s best interests (say, giving up a good entry-level job because he’s been offered a good job in another state), then that’ll lower her pay for the rest of her work life – meaning that the next time such a decision has to be made (and the next, and the next…), her lower salery will seem even more expendable.

Economists call this a “feedback effect”; it’s likely that women earn less because they work less. But it’s also likely that women work less because they earn less.

Cumulative Causation

In 1944, inspired by race riots in Detroit, the influential economist Gunner Myrdal published An American Dilemma, which introduced the concept of “cumulative causation” in discrimination. Although Myrdal was discussing race, the same basic insight can be applied to the wage gap between men and women.

So what does “cumulative causation” mean, in this context? Among other things, it means that the effects of discrimination add up slowly over a lifetime. So, for example, losing a single job offer or promotion probably won’t make a big difference in the short run; but dozens of such small losses over the course of women’s careers eventually add up to a big pay gap.

The economists Robert Wood, Mary Corcoran and Paul Courant examined this question in detail, by looking at the work history of male and female lawyers over time. What they found is that at the start of their careers, women lawyers earned 93% of their male counterparts; but after fifteen years, the women were only earning 61% of what the men made. Even after accounting for hours worked, motherhood, education, and many more factors, women were still being paid only 82% of what similar men took home. (Trish Wilson recently posted more information on this).

Tomorrow I’ll post more on the wage gap, concentrating on refuting some particular anti-feminist arguments. Click on the link below to see the list of references for this post.
Continue reading

Posted in Economics and the like, Gender and the Economy, The Wage Gap Series | 23 Comments

A few quick links.

  • Eve Tushnet has a couple of excellent replies to my post on the SSM debate. The permalinks are bloggered right now, but maybe they’ll be fixed by the time you read this; the first post is here, the second here. Otherwise, just visit Eve’s site and read through the September 23rd entries.

    I’d like to respond to Eve sometime this week, but time is really tight so I can’t promise.

  • Trish Wilson, somewhat inspired by my posts, wrote a good post on the wage gap. And her post on wealth is a must-read, too.
  • Via Trish, I read this excellent post on Keywords about race and the wealth gap. Nothing is more important for understanding the economics of black and white in the USA today than wealth; do read this post.

.

Posted in Site and Admin Stuff | 3 Comments

Trends in the Wage Gap (wage gap series, part 2)

(This is one of a series of posts on the wage gap.)

Changes in the pay gap over time.

In 1972, women working full-time year-round earned 57.9% of what men working full-time year-round earned. In 1999, measured the same way, women earned 72.2% of what men earned. Many people, when they see this data, think that it means that women’s pay has been steadily climbing. But the real story is more complex then that; women’s pay hasn’t risen steadily, and not all of the closing wage gap is because women’s position has improved.

In 1951, women actually earned 63.9% of what mean earned – so women in 1972 actually earned less, compared to men, then women in the 1950s did! Using 1972 as the base year isn’t totally fair, because 1972 had the biggest pay gap between women and men of any year of the last 50 years. But throughout the 1960s and 1970s, the pay gap was always between 58% and 60% – while in the 1950s, the pay gap was usually closer to 64%. So it’s not true that the pay gap has been steadily getting smaller in the last 50 years.

The pay gap didn’t really change much until the 1980s. In 1981, the pay gap was 59.2%; in 1990, it was 71.6%, a change of over 12%. In 1999, on the other hand, the pay gap was 72.2%, a change of less than 1% since 1990.

So the pay gap was more-or-less stable from the 1950s until the 1980s; shrunk quite a lot in the 1980s; and stayed pretty much the same during the 1990s.

wage-gap-gender-1979-99.gif

Women’s rising pay or men’s shrinking pay?

Women’s pay has been going up over time; however, women’s wage growth doesn’t account for all of the shrinking of the pay gap. From 1979 to 1989, the median woman’s hourly wage went up 52 cents (in 1997 dollars). During that same time period, the median man’s hourly wage went down $1.32. From 1989 to 1997, women’s pay went up only 8 cents, while men’s pay fell 88 cents.

What this means is that most of the reason the wage gap is smaller now than it was in 1979 is that men, on average, are being paid less.

Another way of looking at this is to ask: what would have happened to the pay gap if men’s average wages hadn’t fallen? In 1973, an average women’s hourly wage was 63% of an average man’s hourly wage; by 1997, an average women earned 79% of what an average man earned in an hour (a rise of 16%). But if men’s wages hadn’t dropped since 1973, an average woman in 1997 would have earned 67% of what an average man earned in an hour – a rise of only 4% since 1973.

(Data on the pay gap and men’s shrinking pay comes from The State of Working America 1998-1999, by Lawrence Mishel, Jared Bernstein and John Schmitt. Graphic from epinet.org)

Posted in Economics and the like, Gender and the Economy, The Wage Gap Series | Comments Off on Trends in the Wage Gap (wage gap series, part 2)

Reagan's flawed apologetic

Cut on the Bias quotes from a Ronald Reagan apologetic, written in 1978:

“(E)ither he was what he said he was or he was the world’s greatest liar. It is impossible for me to believe a liar or charlatan could have had the effect on mankind that he has had for 2000 years. We could ask, would even the greatest of liars carry his lie through the crucifixion, when a simple confession would have saved him?

Reagan’s logic here is terrible. First of all, he’s assuming that the account of events in the New Testiment is necessarily accurate – but there’s no reason (aside from religious faith) to make that assumption. Secondly, even assuming the NT’s general accuracy, there’s an obvious third possibility besides “messiah” and “charlatan” – Jesus might have been sincere but mistaken about who he was.

Susanna compares Reagan’s logic to C.S. Lewis, but I have a hard time imagining Lewis putting forth an apologetic this unsophisticated. Reagan’s work seems more comparable to Josh McDowell’s..

Posted in Site and Admin Stuff | 11 Comments

Rerun city, Alas

For the coming week – two weeks? month? – there will be rather a lot of posts here which are reprints of things I wrote before starting this blog. Meanwhile, the time that I would otherwise have spent happily blogging will be spent on such joyful tasks as scraping wallpaper paste off of various walls.

I hope people find this an acceptable compromise – I don’t want to put the blog on hiatus altogether, but I definitely don’t have much time for blogging right now.

(I don’t know what Bean has planned, of course – she’s a woman of mystery! – but she’s busy working on the new house too, of course, plus her day job is keeping her extra-busy lately. Which is too bad, since it means that the really cool idea she told me about for a series of posts probably won’t happen for a while.).

Posted in Site and Admin Stuff | 6 Comments

Different ways of measuring the pay gap (wage gap series, part 1)

(This is one of a series of posts on the wage gap.)

There are a literally unlimited number of ways one could go about measuring the pay gap between men and women. Here’s six ways, for example.

  1. Compare wages among young workers only, excluding mothers. (98%)
  2. Compare hourly wages among all workers.
  3. Compare weekly wages among all full-time workers. (76% – pdf file)
  4. Compare annual wages among all full-time, year round (FTYR) workers. (73% – pdf file)
  5. Compare total annual income (wages plus benefits, pension, perks and bonuses) among FTYR workers.
  6. Compare total income over the course of an entire work life.

I’ve arranged this list in order of how big the wage gap is. So if you measure by method number 1, you’ll find a relatively small wage gap – which is why conservatives so often use this method. Measuring with method number 2 will find a larger pay gap than method 1, number 3 will be larger still, and so on until method number 6 – which will find the largest pay gap of all.

The choice of where to measure is, to some degree, arbitrary; no one way of measuring is absolutely correct. Usually, when you see a pay gap figure in the newspaper, it’s measured by the third method I’ve listed – it’s comparing average weekly wages for full-time working women to average weekly wages for full-time working men. The reason most people use this figure is because that’s the way the U.S. government measures it, which means the figure is always conveniently available.

Each of these ways of measuring the pay gap includes and leaves out different things. For instance, if you just compare weekly wages among full-time workers (which is how the government does it), you leave out the value of benefits like medical insurance – but since men are more likely to be in jobs that pay benefits, not including benefits underestimates the size of the pay gap.

On the other hand, a conservative might reply, even among full-time workers men work more hours on average than women, so the weekly wage comparison overestimates the wage gap. (I’ll be responding to this argument later in this series).

The point is, no one way of measuring the wage gap is perfect, or can cover everything. The wage gap is useful as a broad indication of problems that exist in our economy, and as a way of examining how women’s relative pay has changed over time – but it’s not a precise measure.

More on the wage gap tomorrow.

(EDIT: In my first draft, I somehow wrote the same thing, slightly rephrased, for methods one and two. I went back and rewrote them to correct this error…)

Posted in Economics and the like, Gender and the Economy, The Wage Gap Series | 21 Comments

Scattered thoughts on the same-sex marriage debate

You know, “marriage” is one of those words I can never remember how to spell. Is it “marriage” or “marraige”? Sometimes I suspect that other bloggers have this problem too, which is why they refer to it as the “SSM” debate.

Anyhow.

Eve Tushnet writes:

Advocates and opponents of SSM might usefully discuss what they think about children and gender. Should children learn gender roles? Is that harder with a same-sex couple? Is it harder in a society with same-sex marriage? Do those questions matter, and if so, how much?

When social conservatives start talking about the need to teach gender roles, I reach for my gun. People who believe in the importance of teaching “gender roles” create a social context in which unathletic and non-masculine boys are given beatings by their peers.

I think about the years in which I didn’t go a single day without fearing that someone would beat me up, and rarely went an entire week without being physically brutalized by someone (usually, but not always, a boy). After a few years, I internalized so much loathing that I’d stand in front of the mirror, yell at myself, and punch myself in the face; I didn’t even require a bully to be present to get beat up.

And the beatings happened for one reason, and one reason only – because I was unable to decide for myself what was valuable about me as a male. Instead, the people who think it’s important to teach gender roles got to decide – they created a social context in which the punishment of gender role deviants was not only acceptable but encouraged.

Boys will be boys.

Girls will be girls.

And those who don’t fit into the binary will be taught/punished.

Fuck that.

So, to answer Eve’s question, I’m laissez fair when it comes to children’s gender roles. What’s important is providing every child with the individual liberty to act like themselves. If that self fits in with Eve’s conception of proper “gender roles,” fine – but if not, that should be fine too.

The belief that there is a correct “gender role” which must be taught inevitably leads to child abuse, in my opinion.

What always strikes me about the “children must be taught proper gender roles” folks is their lack of faith in the innateness of gender. If masculinity and femininity are really inborn traits, as these folks claim, then why worry about teaching gender roles at all?

* * *

Senator John Cornyn argues that the Supreme Court shouldn’t force SSM onto unwilling states. I agree, if only because I think the backlash from such a Supreme Court decision would fuel the anti-gay-rights movement. For years, the anti-gays have lost every argument and cultural debate on this question; despite their best efforts, lesbians and gays are far more accepted now than they were twenty years ago, and overt homophobia has become almost forbidden. All the trend lines indicate that the folks who favor equal rights are the ones with the wind in our sails, while the folks who oppose equality have been losing their wind for a generation.

I think that without a Supreme Court decision to rail against, the anti-equality movement will die out sooner and more completely.

The Senator also writes:

Another phony argument is the issue of religious freedom. Religious organizations overwhelmingly reported to the subcommittee their support for traditional marriage, and for any legal action necessary to protect traditional marriage. And of course, the Defense of Marriage Act does nothing whatsoever to violate religious freedom. That law focuses entirely on how government shall treat marriage, and not how churches shall treat marriage. Whatever government decides to do about marriage, churches can always make their own decisions, and vice versa. Nobody in Congress is talking about eliminating the right of churches to conduct marriage ceremonies and impose marriage rules of whatever kind they choose.

Of course, nobody in the pro-SSM movement is talking about imposing on churches’ rights, either.

However, what the Senator is talking about is picking and choosing which religions’ marriage ceremonies will be recognized by the state. If the Senator has his way, all of the Catholic Church’s marriage ceremonies will be granted state recognition, but only some Reform Jewish marriages will be given the same recognition. In practice, the state will be saying that Roman Catholic beliefs are superior to and deserve more respect and support than Reform Jewish beliefs.

Probably that doesn’t make the Senator – who I’m willing to bet is not Jewish – nervous, but it does bug me.

* * *

Some of the anti-SSM marriage folks are now turning to the argument that (in Eve’s words) “marriage is how we reconcile the opposite sexes.” I’m very sorry to hear that Eve, who is (I think) unmarried, has no close male friends nor any good relationships with any male relatives, and exists in a state of permanent war with all men. I assure her, however, that this is not the case for all humanity.

To make this argument work, the SSM (same sex marriage) opponents are regressing more and more to pure sexism; their view of the sexes seems to have frozen somewhere around 1952. To see what I mean, read this piece by Rabbi Shmuley Boteach.

If compatibility is the mainstay of a relationship, then homosexuality makes much more sense. After all, two men have a lot more in common than a man and a woman. How many women enjoy watching hours of football, or seeing Mike Tyson tear out an opponent’s spinal cord? And is there a husband who really enjoys spending the day at the mall trying on outfits with his wife?

Why do men and women want to drop their same-sex friends, with whom they have so much in common to spend the rest of their lives with the opposite sex? Why does a man give up his male drinking buddies, hide his inner Neanderthal to go home to his wife? Why would a woman leave the chatty, sympathetic company of her female friends and share her life with a monosyllabic brute?

Is it really necessary to explain why this is nonsense?

When I want to find friends in a strange town, I’m far better off dropping by the local science-fiction club – which is likely to be half female (despite the stereotype, fandom isn’t male-only) – than I am trying to join the local all-male club. For that matter, I’m far better off looking for the local chapter of NOW, which might be 100% female.

The point is, if I search for friends based on my interior life – my enjoyment of science fiction, or my commitment to feminism – I’m far more likely to find people I share things in common with. According to the rabbi, I should just look for an all-male group and I’ll automatically be among my peers – but in reality, men aren’t all the same, and we don’t all have the same interests.

Not all men enjoy watching football and Mike Tyson. Not all women want to spend all day trying on outfits in the mall (and not all men find trying on outfits a bad time).

The Rabbi believes that “two men have a lot more in common than a man and a woman.” Well, which two men and which woman? I suspect I have a lot more in common with Eve Tushnet than I do with (say) Ghengas Khan or Mr. Spock. I know I have a lot more in common with Sarah, my housemate of 14 years, than I do with most men I meet. (I think I may even have a little more in common with her than I do with Charles, Sarah’s husband).

The basic point is, do you think that men and women are individuals, with individual traits (some of which are gender-typed, some of which are not), or robots whose every trait and interest are determined by their genitals?

Apparently, SSM opponents think the latter. How odd.

(In case anyone’s interested, by the way, the Rabbi’s overall argument is that attraction is the key to romance, and that common interests are therefore unimportant. His entire argument thus rests on the unlikely assumption that attraction and common interests are mutually exclusive, so if the one is important the other is not.)

* * *

In the end, this debate really comes down to equal treatment under the law. Which is why SSM opponants say it’s about the children; no, it’s about society; no, it’s about preserving heterosexual monogamy; no, it’s about reconciling women and men; etc etc etc, blah blah blah.

The SSM debate is about equal rights under the law. And SSM opponants are determined to avoid that real debate, because they don’t have any decent arguments in support of lesbians and gays having unequal treatment. That is, in my view, the bottom line..

Posted in Same-Sex Marriage | 54 Comments

Hey, I'm happy to provide amusement

The Modulator is amused by my blogroll’s political classifications. (I should mention that the blogroll is my fault, so if you hate it don’t blame Bean)..

Posted in Site and Admin Stuff | 6 Comments

Double standard?

Kathleen Parker is complaining about double standards among both feminsits and conservative women’s groups:

The important thing is that, when it comes to politics, women’s principles apparently are fungible. Either male hostility (enjoying dunking a woman’s head in the toilet, for instance) is unacceptable or it isn’t. Either sexual harassment in the workplace is unacceptable or it isn’t.

Bill Clinton did have sex with that woman while holding the highest office in the land. He clearly was enjoying one of the perks of power while helping to advance policies that punished lesser mortals for inferior infractions. As a matter of principle, the feminists might have condemned the behavior. (They were mum.)

As for Schwarzenegger, he does have a reputation at least as titillating as Bill Clinton once had, based not on made-up media reports but on the claims of real women from his past. Yet the same crowd that rallied for Paula Jones, Gennifer Flowers, Juanita Broaddrick and others can’t find anything believable among the women who claim that Schwarzenegger groped them.

I’ve got several problems with this.

First of all, Parker seems to assume that all feminist groups (and conservative women’s groups) are interchangeable. For instance, one of the feminist groups she criticizes for attacking Schwarzenegger but not Clinton is CodePink. But CodePink didn’t even exist during Clinton’s administration, so blaming them for not leaping on Monicagate seems unwarranted. Similarly, did the California Federation of Republican Women really criticize Clinton for his treatment of women? Parker doesn’t say, but without establishing that, criticizing the CFRW for their double-standard is premature.

Second, even looking at feminist groups that existed during Clinton’s reign, the idea that they didn’t say a word about Clinton is an antifeminist myth. NOW, for instance, criticized Clinton in harsher terms than any other liberal group I know of: “[Clinton] seems to be a man who divides women into two unfortunate traditional categories: women he must treat with respect like Janet Reno, Madeleine Albright and Ruth Bader Ginsburg, and those he can use and toss aside like tissue paper. We would like better options for president in the future.”

The real complaint seems to be that NOW and other feminists criticized Clinton but did not call for impeachment. But how is that hypocritical? Plenty of right-wing politicians have committed adultery without NOW calling for their impeachment, after all.

Third, there’s an important difference between a candidate for office and a sitting President. Asking “is this candidate a person of good character or a scumbag?” is reasonable during an election, when such criticism might have the practical effect of keeping a scumbag out of office. Once a scumbag is in office, however, yelling “scumbag” over and over won’t change who is in office. When dealing with a sitting president, it makes more sense to criticize his policies than his character, because the policies are much more susceptible to change.

Linked via Sara at Diotima..

Posted in Anti-feminists and their pals, Elections and politics | 29 Comments

Do argicultural subsidies matter much?

There’s lots of fuss in the media about agricultural subsidies… but over at TomPaine.com, in his weekly critique of newspaper stories, economist Dean Baker disagrees.

For example, the September 9th Times piece (which is a lengthy front-page article that also takes up most of an inside page) quotes a vice-president of the World Bank as saying that “reducing these barriers and removing agricultural subsidies is one of the most important things that rich nations can do for millions of people to escape poverty.”

This claim is not supported by research findings. For example, a recent World Bank study found that if rich nations removed all subsidies and barriers affecting merchandise trade (not just agricultural goods), it would raise income in poor countries by just 0.6 percent. This means that if a country had a per capita GDP of $1,000 at present, its income would rise to $1,006 when the full impact of this trade liberalization was felt.

The World Bank’s research actually shows that developing countries would gain far more if rich nations abandoned their efforts to impose U.S.-style patent and copyright protection. While agricultural barriers have been a frequent topic in recent news stories on trade, the much larger economic impact of patent and copyright protection has been completely ignored (see “The Relative Impact of Trade Liberalization on Developing Countries“).

.

Posted in Site and Admin Stuff | 4 Comments